“The Los Angeles freeway system has … changed the way people
think about the urban landscape and therefore about the metropolitan area.
Earlier models of transportation created a multi-centered way of life served by
widespread patterns of movement, but development of the freeway system is the
critical stage in the formalisation of that process. Greater Los Angeles is not
a series of suburbs in close proximity to one another; it is, rather, their
integration into a fluid system of exchanges, of which the freeway system is
the most important nexus … In an area of sprawling suburbanisation and hundreds
of randomly attached communities, the freeway serves to evoke a sense of
clarity and sharpness, to delineate and integrate urban space. It has created a
new sense of space.” [D. Brodsly, ‘L.A. Freeway’, 1981, p.23]
“If I lose my car, I lose my livelihood – period. All I do
is drive my children to school and my wife to work and then myself to work –
each leg is 30 minutes. I do the same again in the evening. If you can’t drive
in the Inland Empire you’re finished.” [quoted in E. Luce, ‘Rebirth of the
American city’, Financial Times, June 8 2013]
“I shall not today attempt further to define the kinds of
material I understand to be embraced within that shorthand description
["hard-core pornography"]; and perhaps I could never succeed in
intelligibly doing so. But I know
it when I see it, and the motion picture involved in this case is not that.” [Emphasis
added.]
—Justice Potter Stewart, concurring opinion in Jacobellis v. Ohio 378 U.S. 184 (1964),
regarding possible obscenity in The Lovers.
I’d like to re-engage a bit with the blog and continue with
an occasional posting. In particular I want to pick up on where the last entry
left off and spend some time over a few entries looking in more detail at the
concept of car-dependent suburbanisation as a “spatial fix”. This was a term
used by David Harvey to describe and analyse the post-WWII car-dependent urban
growth in the US: as we saw, “[t]his arrangement was ‘spatial’ not least
because it entailed a massive physical expansion of cities, and it was a ‘fix’
because it revived real growth in the national economy.” [Hackworth, 2007,
p.78].
One of the points that I argued in the last post was that
the Keynesian “spatial fix” to the Great Depression, manifested particularly in
the US by the technologies of car-dependent suburban sprawl and by the
federal-level planning of the suburban form through, for example, FHA insurance
criteria, mortgage tax subsidies, and freeway construction, provided the
spatial context for a new, decentralised suburban politics dominated by a
middle-class, property-owning, aspirational (and largely white) electorate that
was easily mobilised against explicitly redistributive policy. In the UK, a
similar, though less spatially-distinct, process took place as council tenants
voted for a Conservative party that enabled them to buy the houses in which
they had lived as subsidised tenants.
But it might be a good idea at this point to take a step
back and try to be a bit more precise about some of the terminology we are
using – or at least, using the illustrated blog format, to try to give you a
visual sense of what we are talking about.
What, in particular, do we mean when we talk about
“car-dependent suburbanisation”?
Clearly, suburbanisation is a phenomenon that both long
pre-dates the car and has been intimately connected with the evolution of
transport technology. Let’s start with a couple of longish quotes from Peter
Hall, one of the key thinkers in the field – the first from his superb “Cities
in Civilization” (1998), summarising many of the key points that have been
touched on in earlier blog entries:
“… [G]etting to work is no problem in the village or small
town: a five-minute walk to field or workshop would suffice. … Since a large
and growing part of all employment was found in or near the city centre, this
means that the effective limit of a city’s growth was set by the ability and
the inclination to walk: in practice, as a ready rule of thumb, three miles
(five kilometres), equal to one hour’s travel on foot. Small wonder that as
London doubled prodigiously from one to two million in the first half of the
nineteenth century, people crowded ever more closely near to the centre, and
human misery enormously increased; … exposure to cholera, most dreaded of
Victorian epidemics, was hugely compounded by the phenomenon of population
density and the near-inevitable pollution of water sources that resulted.
Transport technology provided the answer, in the form first
of steam railways and horse buses and streetcars, then electric trains and
subways and motor buses and electric trams, finally the private motor car and
its accompanying highway system. It was urban transport technology which first
allowed the city to sprout suburbs, as in late nineteenth-century London and
New York, and which finally encouraged the suburbs to overwhelm the traditional
city, as in mid-twentieth-century Los Angeles. But this was no easy or
effortless process: it demanded not only great ingenuity in developing the
technologies themselves, but also creativity in devising appropriate
organizational and financial frameworks to bring the new systems into
existence.”[p.612]
The next quote, focusing on the “dialectical” relationship between
the evolution of transport technologies and urban form, is from his paper ‘Squaring
the Circle: Can we Resolve the Clarkian Paradox?’ (1994):
“In 1957 the economist [Colin] Clark published a paper, destined to become a
classic in the urban literature called ‘Transport: maker and breaker of cities’.
In it he argued that – at least since the first industrial revolution, two
hundred years ago – the growth of cities had been shaped by the development of
their transport facilities. But these in turn were dependent on the evolution
of transport technologies. For each successive development of the technology,
there was a corresponding kind of city. However, the relationship was more
complex than that: it was a mutual
one. The transport system shaped the growth of the city, but on the other hand
the previous growth of the city shaped and in particular constrained the
transport alternatives that were available. So the pattern of activities and
land uses in the city, and the transport system, existed in some kind of
symbiotic relationship.
But, Clark stressed, the two could get out of step, and
indeed very often did so. That was particularly the case because cities change
more slowly than the available technologies change”.
I think this is about right: the relationship between
evolving urban form and the “choice” of transport technology is highly
dynamic over time, a "spatial fix" that is like all complex systems subject to multiple positive
feedback loops. In order better to illustrate this point, I think it’s a good
idea to use … illustrations!
In the previous post on the subject of
neoliberalism I quoted from A. Whittemore, (2013), “How the Federal Government
zoned America: The Federal Housing Administration and Zoning.” He uses the
examples of two residential developments in Los Angeles: Leimert Park and
Westchester. The first was begun in 1928, just before the onset of the Great
Depression and already well into the evolution of LA from a city of “streetcar”
suburbs to one of automobile suburbs; the second was developed only a decade
later, beginning in 1938 and expanding rapidly to meet the huge demand created
by the aircraft manufacturing industry in LA in the early 1940s.
What follows
is taken from Wikipedia and Whittemore’s analysis.
Developed by Walter H. Leimert (for
whom it is named) beginning in 1928 and designed by the Olmsted brothers
(sons of New York Central Park designer Frederick Law Olmsted), Leimert Park
was one of the first comprehensively planned communities in Southern California
designed for upper and middle-income families, and was considered a model
of urban planning for its time: automobile
traffic near schools and churches was minimized, utility wires were buried or
hidden from view in alleys, and densely planted trees lined its streets. Walter
Leimert envisioned a self-sufficient community, with a town square, theatre and
retail shopping.
The photo shows a section of Leimert Park, still under development in the 1930s. Intimate in scale, with the commercial area in the upper centre of the photograph, multifamily construction along the radiating arterials, and single-family homes protected on interior streets. Navigable by all personal transportation modes, multiuse, and intimate in scale, it remains an excellent embodiment of the vision of its designers and to a great extent also reflects the ideals to which today’s New Urbanists aspire.
The counterpoint to Leimert Park is, in Whittemore’s view, the “perverted neighborhood unit”: Westchester in 1949, only a few miles to the northwest of Leimert Park. Bloated and dominated by vast sections of single-family use, the Los Angeles Daily News wrote: “You only have to visit Westchester to see the advantage of modern community planning over old-fashioned guesswork methods. In most old communities a hodge-podge of single-family, duplexes, apartments, and business properties are all mixed together.”
Westchester was praised by the planners; described as “low-density
and functionally exclusive”, the boulevards are walled off from the residential
lots backing up to them from interior streets, and the business district is
buffered from the residential areas by parking lots and streets.
Whittemore focuses in his article on the role played by the
Federal Housing Administration, formed in the middle of the 1930s in the
deepest years of the Depression, and charged with providing Federal Government
insurance to residential mortgages that conformed to the building and planning
codes that were established by the FHA itself. He therefore stresses the influence
that the bureaucratic aspects of zoning and the political/consumer demand driven
by the need to access FHA-insured mortgages as key aspects of the evolution of
built form between these two neighbourhoods. One could also look at the role
played by traffic engineers in insisting on wide and relatively straight roads
that would maximise the efficiency of traffic flows as cars evolved rapidly in
terms of speed and sheer numbers on the road.
The key elements in understanding the differences, I would
argue, are the concepts of “mixed use” and “walkability” which have been
fundamental to all the main debates on urban form since the middle of the 20th
century. There is no simple binary distinction between, on the one hand, a
car-dependent, and on the other a “car-independent” suburb. But, to use Justice
Stewart’s famous phrase, “I know it when I see it.”